Optimal defaults and active decisions:
"Defaults can have a dramatic influence on consumer decisions. We identify an overlooked but practical alternative to defaults: requiring individuals to make an explicit choice for themselves. We study such "active decisions" in the context of 401(k) saving. We find that compelling ne...
Gespeichert in:
Format: | Buch |
---|---|
Sprache: | English |
Veröffentlicht: |
Cambridge, Mass.
National Bureau of Economic Research
2005
|
Schriftenreihe: | National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series
11074 |
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | Volltext |
Zusammenfassung: | "Defaults can have a dramatic influence on consumer decisions. We identify an overlooked but practical alternative to defaults: requiring individuals to make an explicit choice for themselves. We study such "active decisions" in the context of 401(k) saving. We find that compelling new hires to make active decisions about 401(k) enrollment raises the initial fraction that enroll by 28 percentage points relative to a standard opt-in enrollment procedure, producing a savings distribution three months after hire that would take three years to achieve under standard enrollment. We also present a model of 401(k) enrollment and derive conditions under which the optimal enrollment regime is automatic enrollment (i.e., default enrollment), standard enrollment (i.e., default non-enrollment), or active decisions (i.e., no default and compulsory choice). Active decisions are optimal when consumers have a strong propensity to procrastinate and savings preferences are highly hetergeneous. Naive beliefs about future time-inconsistency strengthen the normative appeal of the active decision enrollment regime"--National Bureau of Economic Research web site. |
Beschreibung: | 40, [9] S. graph. Darst. |
Internformat
MARC
LEADER | 00000nam a2200000zcb4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
001 | BV023591257 | ||
003 | DE-604 | ||
005 | 20100212 | ||
007 | t | ||
008 | 050204s2005 xxud||| |||| 00||| eng d | ||
035 | |a (OCoLC)57665308 | ||
035 | |a (DE-599)BVBBV023591257 | ||
040 | |a DE-604 |b ger | ||
041 | 0 | |a eng | |
044 | |a xxu |c XD-US | ||
049 | |a DE-521 |a DE-19 | ||
050 | 0 | |a HB1 | |
245 | 1 | 0 | |a Optimal defaults and active decisions |c James J. Choi ... |
264 | 1 | |a Cambridge, Mass. |b National Bureau of Economic Research |c 2005 | |
300 | |a 40, [9] S. |b graph. Darst. | ||
336 | |b txt |2 rdacontent | ||
337 | |b n |2 rdamedia | ||
338 | |b nc |2 rdacarrier | ||
490 | 1 | |a National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series |v 11074 | |
520 | 3 | |a "Defaults can have a dramatic influence on consumer decisions. We identify an overlooked but practical alternative to defaults: requiring individuals to make an explicit choice for themselves. We study such "active decisions" in the context of 401(k) saving. We find that compelling new hires to make active decisions about 401(k) enrollment raises the initial fraction that enroll by 28 percentage points relative to a standard opt-in enrollment procedure, producing a savings distribution three months after hire that would take three years to achieve under standard enrollment. We also present a model of 401(k) enrollment and derive conditions under which the optimal enrollment regime is automatic enrollment (i.e., default enrollment), standard enrollment (i.e., default non-enrollment), or active decisions (i.e., no default and compulsory choice). Active decisions are optimal when consumers have a strong propensity to procrastinate and savings preferences are highly hetergeneous. Naive beliefs about future time-inconsistency strengthen the normative appeal of the active decision enrollment regime"--National Bureau of Economic Research web site. | |
650 | 4 | |a 401(k) plans | |
650 | 4 | |a Finance, Personal |x Decision making | |
700 | 1 | |a Choi, James J. |e Sonstige |0 (DE-588)128782218 |4 oth | |
700 | 1 | |a Laibson, David I. |d 1966- |e Sonstige |0 (DE-588)128782226 |4 oth | |
700 | 1 | |a Madrian, Brigitte C. |d 19XX- |e Sonstige |0 (DE-588)128782234 |4 oth | |
700 | 1 | |a Metrick, Andrew |e Sonstige |0 (DE-588)128782269 |4 oth | |
776 | 0 | 8 | |i Erscheint auch als |n Online-Ausgabe |
830 | 0 | |a National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series |v 11074 |w (DE-604)BV002801238 |9 11074 | |
856 | 4 | 1 | |u http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11074.pdf |z kostenfrei |3 Volltext |
999 | |a oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-016906587 |
Datensatz im Suchindex
_version_ | 1804138248403943424 |
---|---|
adam_txt | |
any_adam_object | |
any_adam_object_boolean | |
author_GND | (DE-588)128782218 (DE-588)128782226 (DE-588)128782234 (DE-588)128782269 |
building | Verbundindex |
bvnumber | BV023591257 |
callnumber-first | H - Social Science |
callnumber-label | HB1 |
callnumber-raw | HB1 |
callnumber-search | HB1 |
callnumber-sort | HB 11 |
callnumber-subject | HB - Economic Theory and Demography |
ctrlnum | (OCoLC)57665308 (DE-599)BVBBV023591257 |
format | Book |
fullrecord | <?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>02606nam a2200385zcb4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">BV023591257</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-604</controlfield><controlfield tag="005">20100212 </controlfield><controlfield tag="007">t</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">050204s2005 xxud||| |||| 00||| eng d</controlfield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(OCoLC)57665308</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)BVBBV023591257</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-604</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1="0" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="044" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">xxu</subfield><subfield code="c">XD-US</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="049" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-521</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-19</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="050" ind1=" " ind2="0"><subfield code="a">HB1</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">Optimal defaults and active decisions</subfield><subfield code="c">James J. Choi ...</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="a">Cambridge, Mass.</subfield><subfield code="b">National Bureau of Economic Research</subfield><subfield code="c">2005</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="300" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">40, [9] S.</subfield><subfield code="b">graph. Darst.</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">n</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">nc</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="490" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series</subfield><subfield code="v">11074</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1="3" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">"Defaults can have a dramatic influence on consumer decisions. We identify an overlooked but practical alternative to defaults: requiring individuals to make an explicit choice for themselves. We study such "active decisions" in the context of 401(k) saving. We find that compelling new hires to make active decisions about 401(k) enrollment raises the initial fraction that enroll by 28 percentage points relative to a standard opt-in enrollment procedure, producing a savings distribution three months after hire that would take three years to achieve under standard enrollment. We also present a model of 401(k) enrollment and derive conditions under which the optimal enrollment regime is automatic enrollment (i.e., default enrollment), standard enrollment (i.e., default non-enrollment), or active decisions (i.e., no default and compulsory choice). Active decisions are optimal when consumers have a strong propensity to procrastinate and savings preferences are highly hetergeneous. Naive beliefs about future time-inconsistency strengthen the normative appeal of the active decision enrollment regime"--National Bureau of Economic Research web site.</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">401(k) plans</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Finance, Personal</subfield><subfield code="x">Decision making</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Choi, James J.</subfield><subfield code="e">Sonstige</subfield><subfield code="0">(DE-588)128782218</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Laibson, David I.</subfield><subfield code="d">1966-</subfield><subfield code="e">Sonstige</subfield><subfield code="0">(DE-588)128782226</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Madrian, Brigitte C.</subfield><subfield code="d">19XX-</subfield><subfield code="e">Sonstige</subfield><subfield code="0">(DE-588)128782234</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Metrick, Andrew</subfield><subfield code="e">Sonstige</subfield><subfield code="0">(DE-588)128782269</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="776" ind1="0" ind2="8"><subfield code="i">Erscheint auch als</subfield><subfield code="n">Online-Ausgabe</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="830" ind1=" " ind2="0"><subfield code="a">National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series</subfield><subfield code="v">11074</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-604)BV002801238</subfield><subfield code="9">11074</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="1"><subfield code="u">http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11074.pdf</subfield><subfield code="z">kostenfrei</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="999" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-016906587</subfield></datafield></record></collection> |
id | DE-604.BV023591257 |
illustrated | Illustrated |
index_date | 2024-07-02T22:41:28Z |
indexdate | 2024-07-09T21:25:10Z |
institution | BVB |
language | English |
oai_aleph_id | oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-016906587 |
oclc_num | 57665308 |
open_access_boolean | 1 |
owner | DE-521 DE-19 DE-BY-UBM |
owner_facet | DE-521 DE-19 DE-BY-UBM |
physical | 40, [9] S. graph. Darst. |
publishDate | 2005 |
publishDateSearch | 2005 |
publishDateSort | 2005 |
publisher | National Bureau of Economic Research |
record_format | marc |
series | National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series |
series2 | National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series |
spelling | Optimal defaults and active decisions James J. Choi ... Cambridge, Mass. National Bureau of Economic Research 2005 40, [9] S. graph. Darst. txt rdacontent n rdamedia nc rdacarrier National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series 11074 "Defaults can have a dramatic influence on consumer decisions. We identify an overlooked but practical alternative to defaults: requiring individuals to make an explicit choice for themselves. We study such "active decisions" in the context of 401(k) saving. We find that compelling new hires to make active decisions about 401(k) enrollment raises the initial fraction that enroll by 28 percentage points relative to a standard opt-in enrollment procedure, producing a savings distribution three months after hire that would take three years to achieve under standard enrollment. We also present a model of 401(k) enrollment and derive conditions under which the optimal enrollment regime is automatic enrollment (i.e., default enrollment), standard enrollment (i.e., default non-enrollment), or active decisions (i.e., no default and compulsory choice). Active decisions are optimal when consumers have a strong propensity to procrastinate and savings preferences are highly hetergeneous. Naive beliefs about future time-inconsistency strengthen the normative appeal of the active decision enrollment regime"--National Bureau of Economic Research web site. 401(k) plans Finance, Personal Decision making Choi, James J. Sonstige (DE-588)128782218 oth Laibson, David I. 1966- Sonstige (DE-588)128782226 oth Madrian, Brigitte C. 19XX- Sonstige (DE-588)128782234 oth Metrick, Andrew Sonstige (DE-588)128782269 oth Erscheint auch als Online-Ausgabe National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series 11074 (DE-604)BV002801238 11074 http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11074.pdf kostenfrei Volltext |
spellingShingle | Optimal defaults and active decisions National Bureau of Economic Research <Cambridge, Mass.>: NBER working paper series 401(k) plans Finance, Personal Decision making |
title | Optimal defaults and active decisions |
title_auth | Optimal defaults and active decisions |
title_exact_search | Optimal defaults and active decisions |
title_exact_search_txtP | Optimal defaults and active decisions |
title_full | Optimal defaults and active decisions James J. Choi ... |
title_fullStr | Optimal defaults and active decisions James J. Choi ... |
title_full_unstemmed | Optimal defaults and active decisions James J. Choi ... |
title_short | Optimal defaults and active decisions |
title_sort | optimal defaults and active decisions |
topic | 401(k) plans Finance, Personal Decision making |
topic_facet | 401(k) plans Finance, Personal Decision making |
url | http://papers.nber.org/papers/w11074.pdf |
volume_link | (DE-604)BV002801238 |
work_keys_str_mv | AT choijamesj optimaldefaultsandactivedecisions AT laibsondavidi optimaldefaultsandactivedecisions AT madrianbrigittec optimaldefaultsandactivedecisions AT metrickandrew optimaldefaultsandactivedecisions |