Towards global carbon pricing: Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets
Emissions trading systems (ETS) can play a major role in a cost-effective climate policy framework. Both direct linking of ETSs and indirect linking through a common crediting mechanism can reduce costs of action.We use a global recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model to assess the ef...
Gespeichert in:
1. Verfasser: | |
---|---|
Weitere Verfasser: | , , |
Format: | Elektronisch Buchkapitel |
Sprache: | English |
Veröffentlicht: |
Paris
OECD Publishing
2014
|
Schlagworte: | |
Online-Zugang: | DE-384 DE-473 DE-824 DE-29 DE-739 DE-355 DE-20 DE-1028 DE-1049 DE-521 DE-861 DE-898 DE-92 DE-91 DE-573 DE-19 URL des Erstveröffentlichers |
Zusammenfassung: | Emissions trading systems (ETS) can play a major role in a cost-effective climate policy framework. Both direct linking of ETSs and indirect linking through a common crediting mechanism can reduce costs of action.We use a global recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model to assess the effects of direct and indirect linking of ETS systems across world regions. Linking of domestic Annex I ETSs leads to moderate aggregate cost savings, as differences in domestic permit prices are limited. Countries benefit directly from linking by either buying permits and avoiding investing in highcost mitigation options, or by exploiting relatively cheap mitigation options and selling permits at a higher price. Although the economy of the main permit sellers, such as Russia, is negatively affected by the real exchange rate appreciation that is induced by the large export of permits, on balance they also still benefit from linking. The costsaving potential for developed countries of well-functioning crediting mechanisms appears to be very large. Even limited use of credits would nearly halve mitigation costs; cost savings would be largest for carbon-intensive economies. However, one open issue iswhether these gains can be fully reaped in reality, given that direct linking and the use of crediting mechanisms both raise complex system design and implementation issues. The analysis in this paper shows, however, that the potential gains to be reaped are so large, that substantial efforts in this domain are warranted. JEL classification: H23, O41, Q54 Keywords: Climate mitigation policy, emissions trading systems, general equilibrium models, linking carbon markets |
Beschreibung: | 1 Online-Ressource (26 Seiten) 21 x 28cm |
DOI: | 10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |
Internformat
MARC
LEADER | 00000nma a2200000zc 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
001 | BV047938201 | ||
003 | DE-604 | ||
007 | cr|uuu---uuuuu | ||
008 | 220413s2014 |||| o||u| ||||||eng d | ||
024 | 7 | |a 10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |2 doi | |
035 | |a (ZDB-13-SOC)061321141 | ||
035 | |a (DE-599)BVBBV047938201 | ||
040 | |a DE-604 |b ger |e aacr | ||
041 | 0 | |a eng | |
049 | |a DE-384 |a DE-91 |a DE-473 |a DE-824 |a DE-29 |a DE-739 |a DE-355 |a DE-20 |a DE-1028 |a DE-1049 |a DE-188 |a DE-521 |a DE-861 |a DE-898 |a DE-92 |a DE-573 |a DE-19 | ||
100 | 1 | |a Dellink, Rob |e Verfasser |4 aut | |
245 | 1 | 0 | |a Towards global carbon pricing |b Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |c Rob Dellink ... [et al] |
264 | 1 | |a Paris |b OECD Publishing |c 2014 | |
300 | |a 1 Online-Ressource (26 Seiten) |c 21 x 28cm | ||
336 | |b txt |2 rdacontent | ||
337 | |b c |2 rdamedia | ||
338 | |b cr |2 rdacarrier | ||
520 | |a Emissions trading systems (ETS) can play a major role in a cost-effective climate policy framework. Both direct linking of ETSs and indirect linking through a common crediting mechanism can reduce costs of action.We use a global recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model to assess the effects of direct and indirect linking of ETS systems across world regions. Linking of domestic Annex I ETSs leads to moderate aggregate cost savings, as differences in domestic permit prices are limited. Countries benefit directly from linking by either buying permits and avoiding investing in highcost mitigation options, or by exploiting relatively cheap mitigation options and selling permits at a higher price. Although the economy of the main permit sellers, such as Russia, is negatively affected by the real exchange rate appreciation that is induced by the large export of permits, on balance they also still benefit from linking. The costsaving potential for developed countries of well-functioning crediting mechanisms appears to be very large. Even limited use of credits would nearly halve mitigation costs; cost savings would be largest for carbon-intensive economies. However, one open issue iswhether these gains can be fully reaped in reality, given that direct linking and the use of crediting mechanisms both raise complex system design and implementation issues. The analysis in this paper shows, however, that the potential gains to be reaped are so large, that substantial efforts in this domain are warranted. JEL classification: H23, O41, Q54 Keywords: Climate mitigation policy, emissions trading systems, general equilibrium models, linking carbon markets | ||
650 | 4 | |a Economics | |
700 | 1 | |a Jamet, Stéphanie |4 ctb | |
700 | 1 | |a Chateau, Jean |4 ctb | |
700 | 1 | |a Duval, Romain |4 ctb | |
856 | 4 | 0 | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |x Verlag |z URL des Erstveröffentlichers |3 Volltext |
912 | |a ebook | ||
943 | 1 | |a oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-033319695 | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-384 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-473 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-824 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-29 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-739 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-355 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-20 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-1028 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-1049 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-521 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-861 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-898 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-92 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-91 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-573 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext | |
966 | e | |u https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |l DE-19 |p ZDB-13-SOC |x Verlag |3 Volltext |
Datensatz im Suchindex
_version_ | 1815091526239256576 |
---|---|
adam_text | |
adam_txt | |
any_adam_object | |
any_adam_object_boolean | |
author | Dellink, Rob |
author2 | Jamet, Stéphanie Chateau, Jean Duval, Romain |
author2_role | ctb ctb ctb |
author2_variant | s j sj j c jc r d rd |
author_facet | Dellink, Rob Jamet, Stéphanie Chateau, Jean Duval, Romain |
author_role | aut |
author_sort | Dellink, Rob |
author_variant | r d rd |
building | Verbundindex |
bvnumber | BV047938201 |
collection | ebook |
ctrlnum | (ZDB-13-SOC)061321141 (DE-599)BVBBV047938201 |
discipline | Wirtschaftswissenschaften |
discipline_str_mv | Wirtschaftswissenschaften |
doi_str_mv | 10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |
format | Electronic Book Chapter |
fullrecord | <?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>00000nma a2200000zc 4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">BV047938201</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-604</controlfield><controlfield tag="007">cr|uuu---uuuuu</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">220413s2014 |||| o||u| ||||||eng d</controlfield><datafield tag="024" ind1="7" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="2">doi</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(ZDB-13-SOC)061321141</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)BVBBV047938201</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-604</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield><subfield code="e">aacr</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1="0" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="049" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-384</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-91</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-473</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-824</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-29</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-739</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-355</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-20</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-1028</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-1049</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-188</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-521</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-861</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-898</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-92</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-573</subfield><subfield code="a">DE-19</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="100" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Dellink, Rob</subfield><subfield code="e">Verfasser</subfield><subfield code="4">aut</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">Towards global carbon pricing</subfield><subfield code="b">Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets</subfield><subfield code="c">Rob Dellink ... [et al]</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="a">Paris</subfield><subfield code="b">OECD Publishing</subfield><subfield code="c">2014</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="300" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">1 Online-Ressource (26 Seiten)</subfield><subfield code="c">21 x 28cm</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">c</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="b">cr</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Emissions trading systems (ETS) can play a major role in a cost-effective climate policy framework. Both direct linking of ETSs and indirect linking through a common crediting mechanism can reduce costs of action.We use a global recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model to assess the effects of direct and indirect linking of ETS systems across world regions. Linking of domestic Annex I ETSs leads to moderate aggregate cost savings, as differences in domestic permit prices are limited. Countries benefit directly from linking by either buying permits and avoiding investing in highcost mitigation options, or by exploiting relatively cheap mitigation options and selling permits at a higher price. Although the economy of the main permit sellers, such as Russia, is negatively affected by the real exchange rate appreciation that is induced by the large export of permits, on balance they also still benefit from linking. The costsaving potential for developed countries of well-functioning crediting mechanisms appears to be very large. Even limited use of credits would nearly halve mitigation costs; cost savings would be largest for carbon-intensive economies. However, one open issue iswhether these gains can be fully reaped in reality, given that direct linking and the use of crediting mechanisms both raise complex system design and implementation issues. The analysis in this paper shows, however, that the potential gains to be reaped are so large, that substantial efforts in this domain are warranted. JEL classification: H23, O41, Q54 Keywords: Climate mitigation policy, emissions trading systems, general equilibrium models, linking carbon markets</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economics</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Jamet, Stéphanie</subfield><subfield code="4">ctb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Chateau, Jean</subfield><subfield code="4">ctb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Duval, Romain</subfield><subfield code="4">ctb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="0"><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="z">URL des Erstveröffentlichers</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">ebook</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="943" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-033319695</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-384</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-473</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-824</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-29</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-739</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-355</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-20</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-1028</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-1049</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-521</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-861</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-898</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-92</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-91</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-573</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="966" ind1="e" ind2=" "><subfield code="u">https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb</subfield><subfield code="l">DE-19</subfield><subfield code="p">ZDB-13-SOC</subfield><subfield code="x">Verlag</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield></record></collection> |
id | DE-604.BV047938201 |
illustrated | Not Illustrated |
index_date | 2024-07-03T19:35:08Z |
indexdate | 2024-11-07T19:02:50Z |
institution | BVB |
language | English |
oai_aleph_id | oai:aleph.bib-bvb.de:BVB01-033319695 |
open_access_boolean | |
owner | DE-384 DE-91 DE-BY-TUM DE-473 DE-BY-UBG DE-824 DE-29 DE-739 DE-355 DE-BY-UBR DE-20 DE-1028 DE-1049 DE-188 DE-521 DE-861 DE-898 DE-BY-UBR DE-92 DE-573 DE-19 DE-BY-UBM |
owner_facet | DE-384 DE-91 DE-BY-TUM DE-473 DE-BY-UBG DE-824 DE-29 DE-739 DE-355 DE-BY-UBR DE-20 DE-1028 DE-1049 DE-188 DE-521 DE-861 DE-898 DE-BY-UBR DE-92 DE-573 DE-19 DE-BY-UBM |
physical | 1 Online-Ressource (26 Seiten) 21 x 28cm |
psigel | ebook ZDB-13-SOC |
publishDate | 2014 |
publishDateSearch | 2014 |
publishDateSort | 2014 |
publisher | OECD Publishing |
record_format | marc |
spelling | Dellink, Rob Verfasser aut Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets Rob Dellink ... [et al] Paris OECD Publishing 2014 1 Online-Ressource (26 Seiten) 21 x 28cm txt rdacontent c rdamedia cr rdacarrier Emissions trading systems (ETS) can play a major role in a cost-effective climate policy framework. Both direct linking of ETSs and indirect linking through a common crediting mechanism can reduce costs of action.We use a global recursive-dynamic computable general equilibrium model to assess the effects of direct and indirect linking of ETS systems across world regions. Linking of domestic Annex I ETSs leads to moderate aggregate cost savings, as differences in domestic permit prices are limited. Countries benefit directly from linking by either buying permits and avoiding investing in highcost mitigation options, or by exploiting relatively cheap mitigation options and selling permits at a higher price. Although the economy of the main permit sellers, such as Russia, is negatively affected by the real exchange rate appreciation that is induced by the large export of permits, on balance they also still benefit from linking. The costsaving potential for developed countries of well-functioning crediting mechanisms appears to be very large. Even limited use of credits would nearly halve mitigation costs; cost savings would be largest for carbon-intensive economies. However, one open issue iswhether these gains can be fully reaped in reality, given that direct linking and the use of crediting mechanisms both raise complex system design and implementation issues. The analysis in this paper shows, however, that the potential gains to be reaped are so large, that substantial efforts in this domain are warranted. JEL classification: H23, O41, Q54 Keywords: Climate mitigation policy, emissions trading systems, general equilibrium models, linking carbon markets Economics Jamet, Stéphanie ctb Chateau, Jean ctb Duval, Romain ctb https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb Verlag URL des Erstveröffentlichers Volltext |
spellingShingle | Dellink, Rob Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets Economics |
title | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
title_auth | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
title_exact_search | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
title_exact_search_txtP | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
title_full | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets Rob Dellink ... [et al] |
title_fullStr | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets Rob Dellink ... [et al] |
title_full_unstemmed | Towards global carbon pricing Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets Rob Dellink ... [et al] |
title_short | Towards global carbon pricing |
title_sort | towards global carbon pricing direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
title_sub | Direct and indirect linking of carbon markets |
topic | Economics |
topic_facet | Economics |
url | https://doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2013-5k421kk9j3vb |
work_keys_str_mv | AT dellinkrob towardsglobalcarbonpricingdirectandindirectlinkingofcarbonmarkets AT jametstephanie towardsglobalcarbonpricingdirectandindirectlinkingofcarbonmarkets AT chateaujean towardsglobalcarbonpricingdirectandindirectlinkingofcarbonmarkets AT duvalromain towardsglobalcarbonpricingdirectandindirectlinkingofcarbonmarkets |